Marielle Martin – Lesson 3

The government has the ability to impose policy to incentives and disincentives certain behaviors. When it is a public goods issue, as this one is, imposing these policies is justifiable. A carbon tax is a large scale measure, being heavily analyzed at the present. Dale Jorgenson, and economist who studies the relationships between energy, policy, and environment, spoke in an interview about the tax. He (2014) noted that “a tax of $30 per metric ton of carbon dioxide is equivalent to a tax of 24.4 cents per gallon of gasoline”, which would “raise about $150 billion in revenue for the United States” (Shaw). The article also estimates the world’s yearly costs of climate change impacts to be around $1.6 trillion dollars (Shaw, 2014). With that in mind, the tax is actually hugely discounted to what we actually ‘owe’ the planet. In addition to the carbon tax, policies providing tax credits, grants, or home and business certifications based on energy use thresholds, high efficiency, or low emission/renewable energy source use could be applied. The metrics for these policies may be difficult to accurately measure though, as people have the ability to use a variety of energy options – only some of which require metering/grid connection that is monitored. As a last resort option, government policy could take a glance back in time to the 1970s. Oil economics and foreign power plays resulted in gasoline rationing in the United States. It’s a drastic measure, but there may be a day when such drastic measures are once again necessary. This type of government policy would surely ruffle some feathers over the issues of ‘freedom’ and ‘market economy’. It would span a much more diverse range of energy options to place restrictions on and have social implications on issues like income, standard of living, and access to alternatives.

To develop a business that works through government policy for energy efficiency, I would want to first identify where policy may be viable. I would be inclined to work on designing, building, or installing a measurement technology that could be used in policy aimed to incentivize household efforts for efficiency and minimizing consumption. As I mentioned above, measuring the metrics for which incentives would be rewarded can be difficult, so the prospect of policy only matters if the tools to provide the policy exist. In the hands of private business, innovative solutions for measuring a household’s energy use – even down to the type of energy – may be possible. In the UK, government is promoting smart meter installation in all homes and businesses by 2020 to increase energy conservation (Morris, 2014). The technology developed by Smart Metering Systems monitors gas and electricity consumption, sends the information to energy companies, and provides users with real consumption measurements (Morris, 2014). Smart Metering Systems’ profits have risen by 24% since government promotion began – proving that certain policy has the opportunity to create positive change (Morris, 2014). In addition to the initial energy conservation that users proactively achieve from smart meter installation, policy implementation to reward conservation efforts (by tax credit, grant, etc.) based on energy consumption ‘brackets’ would further increase energy conservation. For example, lower levels of energy consumption would correspond to higher levels of tax credit off of energy spending. The “kilowatt not used is the best of all” would definitely apply for a business working with government policy to conserve energy.

Shaw, Jonathan. (2014, September-October). Time to Tax Carbon. Harvard Magazine. Retrieved from http://harvardmag.com/pdf/2014/09-pdfs/0914-52.pdf

Morris, Jessica. (2014, September 2). Smart Metering Systems Rise on U.K. Energy Savings Plan. Businessweek. Retrieved from http://www.businessweek.com/news/2014-09-02/smart-metering-systems-rises-on-u-dot-k-dot-energy-savings-plan

 

2 thoughts on “Marielle Martin – Lesson 3

  1. I agree there is insufficient incentive for households and businesses to cut emissions. In order to stimulate efficient energy use there must be a policy to get the “polluters” to pay. However I do differ with you on how to accomplish this. Cap and trade seems to provide an easier transition for businesses to cut emissions than a carbon tax. With a tax there is an immediate cost that will affect the bottom line of companies. Whereas with a cap and trade only those businesses that exceed their allowance would have an outlay for emissions. Also with a tax, the price for emissions is set without limitation for emissions. Cap and trade allows the free-market to set the price for excess emissions and has a definite limit on allowable emissions. Both programs would be beneficial for the environment; it just comes down to feasibility.

    Here is a link to my post, if interested: http://engr312.dutton.psu.edu/2014/09/15/lesson-3-energy-efficiency-developing-reliable-ccs-rob-fulton/

    Best,

    Rob

  2. (your skipping ahead I see!!)…I had to read your post because you are in my Geog 438W group!!! haha. Your writing is truly collegiate. I am on lesson 2 actually and answered the 2.8 blog post. I have included my link. I’m going to look around for your 2.8 post. I really enjoy your writing, organization and structure. It’s not overwhelming which many policy writers need to keep in mind. That’s all I can really say at this moment as I am not on Lesson 3 yet. I’ll complete 3 and re-read this post….

    Permalink: http://sites.psu.edu/engr312/2014/09/09/david-westsmit…ding-the-niche/

Leave a Reply